In the seminal paper of Duffie, et al.[undefined], the class of affine processes is extensively explored and motivated with examples of applications to finance. From the perspective of the moment generating function, an affine process $X$ on $\bbR^d$ is characterized very succinctly—it is Markov and satsifies the following affine transform formula.
$$\rmE\Big( e^{u^\T X_T} | X_t = x \Big) = \exp\Big(\psi_0(t, T, u) + \psi(t, T, u)^\T x \Big), \quad u \in i\bbR^d $$
Here, we are adopting the slightly more general time-inhomogeneous case discussed in Filipović[undefined]. There are some great papers (for instance, [undefined], [undefined]) that subsequently study these objects—be it generalizing results, weakening hypotheses, focusing on specific cases, or studying related statistical procedures. Each of these acknowledge a very important result about affine processes: the transition semigroup from $X$ and affine transform formula above induces dynamics on $\psi_0, \psi_1$ which ultimately boil down to an integro-differential equation.
$$\left\{\begin{array}{ll} \displaystyle \frac{\partial}{\partial t} \psi_0(t, T, u) = -R_0\big(t, \psi(t, T, u)\big) & \psi_0(T, T, u) = 0 \\[1em] \displaystyle \frac{\partial}{\partial t} \psi(t, T, u) = -R(t, \psi(t, T, u)\big) & \psi(T, T, u) = u \end{array}\right.$$$$R_i(s, u) = \frac12 u^\T a_i(s) u + u^\T b_i(s) + \int_{\bbR^d} \big( e^{u^\T y} - 1 - 1_{\lVert y \rVert \leq 1} u^\T y \big) m_i(s, {\rm d}y) , \quad i = 0, \ldots, d $$for symmetric-positive-definite-valued functions $a_0, \ldots, a_d: \bbR_+ \rightarrow S_d^+$, vector-valued functions $b_0,\ldots, b_d: \bbR_+ \rightarrow \bbR^d$, and time-varying Radon measures, $m_0, \ldots, m_d: \bbR_+ \times \calR^d \rightarrow \bbR_+$ on the Borel sets $\calR^d$. This offers a parameterization for affine processes—any such collection of functions induce a differential equation of which there is a corresponding affine process satisfying the affine transform formula. The point of this post is to explain how these parameters manifest as a stochastic differential equation for $X$ when it has finite activity.Let us assume that $m_0(s, \cdot), \ldots, m_d(s, \cdot)$ are finite measures for all $s \geq 0$. With such an assumption, we may define the total measures $k_i(s) = m_i(s, \bbR^d) \in (0,\infty)$ and factor out probability measures $\nu_i(s, \cdot)$ like so.
$$ m_i(s, {\rm d}y) = k_i(s) \nu_i(s, {\rm d}y) $$Additionally, this assumption allows us to reparameterize our vector-valued functions $b_i$
$$ b_i(s) \leftarrow b_i(s) - \int_{\bbR^d} 1_{\lVert y \rVert \leq 1} y m_i(s, {\rm d}y) $$so that each $R_i$ may be rewritten more succinctly.
$$ R_i(s, u) = \frac12 u^\T a_i(s) u + u^\T b_i(s) + \int_{\bbR^d} \big( e^{u^\T y} - 1 \big) k_i(s) \nu_i(s, {\rm d}y) $$With such functions, we may consider a stochastic process $X$ solving the following differential equation for a filtration $\calF$
$$ X_t = X_0 + \int_0^t \beta(s, X_s) {\rm d}s + \int_0^t \sigma(s, X_s) {\rm d}W_s + \int_{[0,t] \times \bbR^d} y \mu({\rm d}s \times {\rm d}y) $$where $\sigma$ is some function satisfying $\sigma\sigma^\T = \alpha$, $W$ is a standard $\calF$-Brownian motion on $\bbR^d$, and $\mu$ is an integer-valued random measure with $\calF$-compensator $\mu^P$ as so.
$$ \mu^P({\rm d}s \times {\rm d}y) = \kappa(s, X_{s-}, {\rm d}y) {\rm d}s$$A solution $X$ to this stochastic differential equation will be an affine process with the same parameters in the affine transform formula.